I demolished no less than 38 spurious arguments against
narrow banking here
recently. But the rubbish arguments just keep coming.
The latest examples in this genre I’ve stumbled across are
in an article
by the above two authors. (Incidentally, I’ll use the phrase “full reserve
banking” instead of “narrow banking”. But the system referred to is exactly
what C&S refer to, namely the proposals for bank reform put by Lawrence Kotlikoff, John Cochrane, Martin Wolf and others cited
by C&S)
Indeed, the sheer number of spurious arguments put against
full reserve is evidence that the opposition to it is PSYCHOLOGICAL rather than
rational. To illustrate, there were very roughly five not bad arguments both
for and against invading Iraq ten years ago. But once you get beyond roughly
five, you’re into nutter territory.
Cecchetti and Schoenholtz clearly haven’t much grasp of the
basics of full reserve, which are incidentally simple enough: I set out the
basics in a few hundred words starting on p.4 here.
Anyway, Cecchetti and Schoenholtz’s mistakes are as follows.
Replicating existing bank activities.
They claim that, “Banks serve capitalist economies in two
ways that are costly to replicate. First, they are experts in providing
liquidity both to depositors and to borrowers.”
So you have to be an “expert” to supply an economy with
liquidity? Hilarious. All you need is a government and central bank that prints
and spends money into the economy in whatever quantities the economy needs.
Printing and spending money is idiot’s work. As for gauging exactly the right
amount to print and spend, that’s clearly more difficult. But then governments
struggle to get the amount of stimulus right ANYWAY. So full reserve is not
inferior to the existing system in that respect. (Incidentally “print and spend”
tends to be the form of stimulus favoured by full reservers, and that actually
comes to the same thing as a form of stimulus implemented recently, i.e. fiscal
stimulus followed by quantitative easing.)
Costs.
As for “costly”, the real costs of having commercial banks
supply an economy with money or “liquidity” are quite clearly higher than
having a central bank do the job. Reason is that commercial banks have to check
up on the value of collateral supplied by would-be borrowers. In contrast,
there is no need for a central bank to do that: it simply prints and spends
money into the economy in whatever quantity keeps employment as high as
possible without bringing excess inflation.
Liquidity for borrowers.
As for Cecchetti and Schoenholtz’s claim that supplying
borrowers with liquidity is difficult to “replicate”, that point is nonsense,
because under full reserve, the lending half of the banking industry lends in
exactly the same way as banks currently lend: that is, it looks at the
creditworthiness of potential borrowers and lends (or doesn’t) accordingly.
I.e. there is no need to “replicate”. Put another way, and using C&S’s
phraseology, banks would “screen potential borrowers” just as they do now.
Runs.
Next, comes what C&S call their “main point” namely that
given poor performance by a bank or “lending entity” under full reserve, a run
on its shares would be as likely as traditional bank runs.
Well the first answer to that is that runs on stock exchange
quoted shares just don’t happen. Reason is that given bad news about a firm or corporation,
the value of its shares drop before anyone has time to sell (with the possible
exception of some inside traders).
Second, even if a run did take place, there is a HUGE
DIFFERENCE between a traditional bank run and a run on bank shares under full
reserve: the former leads to the bank going bust or going insolvent, while the
latter does not. C&S are oblivious of that difference.
Withdrawals.
C&S then say, “collective attempts at liquidation to
meet withdrawal requests would lead to ruinous fire sales.” What in God’s name
are they on about?
What’s the phrase “withdrawal request” doing there? A share
in a corporation does not involve the corporation owing shareholders one cent.
If a larger than normal set of shareholders want out, then the value of the
shares drop. There is no need for the corporation (banking corporation or any
other corporation) to “meet withdrawal requests”).
C&S are obviously confused as to the difference between
the two halves of the banking industry under full reserve. That is, the safe
half clearly faces “withdrawal requests” but it can always meet them because
the relevant money is lodged in a totally safe manner. As to the investment or
lending half, the value of its assets can collapse, but it never faces “withdrawal
requests”.
Illiquid mutual funds.
And finally C&S cite “research” which shows allegedly
that the price of mutual funds which hold illiquid assets is more volatile than
cash mutual funds. Well – revelation of the century!!!!
The value of a $100 stake in a cash mutual fund should, if
the fund is well run, always remain very near to $100. In contrast, funds that
invest say in stock exchange quoted shares will be more volatile. But that’s a
risk that shareholders deliberately and knowingly accept, in the hopes that
accepting that risk leads to a decent return on capital in the long term.
You really have to wonder what C&S think they’re doing
writing an article on banking, don’t you? Still, academics are rewarded in proportion to
the QUANTITY of verbiage they churn out, not the QUALITY. So no doubt the above
article will improve C&S’s CVs.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Post a comment.